FUTURE LAND USE PLANNING ALTERNATIVES
FOR ALASKA
One of a series of Articles on
THE NATIVE LAND CLAIMS
By
Walter B. Parker
Associate in Systems Planning
Arctic Environmental Information
and Data Center, University of Alaska
One of a Series of Articles on
THE NATIVE LAND CLAIMS
COMPILED & PRODUCED
JOINTLY BY
ALASKA DEPARTMENT OF EDUCATION
AND
CENTER FOR NORTHERN EDUCATIONAL RESEARCH
UNIVERSITY OF ALASKA - FAIRBANKS
Dr. Marshall L. Lind
Commissioner of Education
Frank Darnell
Director, Center for Northern Educational Research
ARTWORK: CANDACE OWERS
JUNE 1975
TO THE READER
This booklet is one of a collection of articles written by people
who are interested in Native land claims. As you will see, all of the
people do not agree. They present their ideas for you to read and
discuss. You may be excited about some of their ideas because you
think they are absolutely right, or very wrong. When you have
finished reading the articles, you will probably have done a lot of
thinking about Native land claims and Alaskan politics.
Politics is not an easy field to understand. And yet politics is
what the Native land claims are all about. Most of the articles were
written by people who have spent a lot of time working in the world
of politics. These people have a whole vocabulary which most students
have not yet learned. So, to help students understand the reading,
there is at the beginning of each article a list of definitions of
terms. Any words in italics are explained for you at the beginning of
that article, or an earlier one.
At the end of some articles are questions which you can ask
yourself. In the margin, next to the question are numbers. If you go
back to paragraphs in the article with the same numbers, and reread,
you can increase your understanding. We cannot say you will always
have definite answers but you may form your point of view.
ARTICLES AND AUTHORS
FUTURE LAND USE PLANNING ALTERNATIVES FOR ALASKA
Land planning in Alaska has come to be a synonym for regional
planning. Seldom has regional planning, on such a scale and with such
a time frame, been attempted anywhere prior to this time. The Alaska
Native Claims Settlement Act mandated that a Joint Federal-State Land
Use Planning Commission would be established to carry out certain
aspects of the Act. Due to the amount of land involved, this
commission has become in effect, a regional planning commission, but
with advisory powers only. The true planning powers remain with the
State of Alaska, incorporated municipalities, and the federal land
owning agencies in Alaska.
The basic planning framework established in the State of Alaska by
its constitution is better than that which exists in most of the
other states Failures of planning in Alaska can usually be attributed
to lack of will on the part of its administrators and land owners
rather than any institutional barrier to good planning.
The Alaska Statehood Act gave the state the right to select up to
103 million acres of the state's 375 million acre total. The land law
statues developed by the state to govern the administration of its
lands call for land to be classified for use prior to sale, a
factor not yet present in the federal and many state land laws to the
necessary degree. In addition, the state land laws required purchase
of state lands with provisions that some development costs could
offset the purchase price. This supposedly insured that land would
not be taken up and held for speculation. But it has not worked to
the degree it was hoped, since large quantities of state land in the
Matanuska Valley have been bought by speculators and are being held
by them. In the first 12 years of statehood (up until 1968), Alaska
had selected only 21 million acres of its patrimony.
In 1968 the rest of the land was in federal ownership with the
exception of less than one million acres in private holdings as a
result of lands homesteaded under the Homestead Act, or those
purchased from the state. Of the federal lands the great bulk, 272
million acres, was unreserved public domain under control of the
Bureau of Land Management with 86 million acres under control of the
Forest Service. This 86 million acres is distributed as follows:
Forest Service (20.7 million acres), Bureau of Sportfish and Wild
life (18.6 million acres), the Department of Defense (26.2 million
acres), the National Park Service (6.9 million acres) and other
withdrawals for power reserves and Natives amounting to 13.4 million
acres. 1
The planning function in the State of Alaska is centralized in the
Office of the Governor in a Division of Planning and Research. This
office is supposed to coordinate all planning of municipalities and
the various state agencies. It accomplishes this function to the best
of its ability but is chronically understaffed.
Alaska has made provisions for regional planning since its borough
structure makes planning powers mandatory incorporated boroughs.
Boroughs were required to exercise not only the regional planning
function but also to take care of planning and zoning for the cities
located within the borough structure. However, cities were permitted
to retain their own zoning adjustment boards. The first borough was
incorporated in 1962 and at present there are nine which occupy some
98,000 square miles or 17 percent of the state's land area which
contain 260,000 (79 percent) of the state's 330,000 population.
The rest of the state relies upon first class and second class
cities to exercise local jurisdiction while the state Department of
Community and Regional Affairs operates the planning function for the
unorganized borough. The governing body for the unorganized borough
is the state legislature.
As shown above, the Alaska statutes do provide for a reasonable
structure from which coordinated planning can be accomplished. The
missing ingredient is a means of coordinating planning for the
federal agencies which still control the great bulk of the state's
land. A vehicle once existed in the Federal Field Committee for
Development Planning in Alaska, which was created after the Alaska
earthquake in 1964, to coordinate relief and rehabilitation programs
in the state. While this committee had no direct control over its
member agencies, it was able to coordinate in major areas which cut
across agency missions. I he Alaska Native Claims Settlement Act was
initially coordinated by the committee and it was responsible for the
background data and early legislative efforts on that historic act.
The Federal Field Committee was dissolved by executive order in 1971.
The Native Claims Settlement Act institutes land patterns in
Alaska which will shape the state in every facet for the next several
centuries. It distributes over a five-year period 40 million acres of
land to private citizens on an ethnic basis and it provides for an
additional 80 million acres of specially designated federal lands.
Thus, the configuration of Alaska by December 1976, when these
designations will have been largely finalized, will resemble
something of the following.
(millions of acres)
|
1970 |
1976 |
State Land
|
27
|
103
|
Private Land
|
1
|
41
|
Federal Special Use
|
86
|
152
|
Total
|
375
|
375
|
The great unreserved federal public domain which every Alaskan and
thus every American could look upon as his own will be reduced by two
thirds. While it will be replaced in large part by public lands,
these will be managed for particular purposes and the many uses which
were permitted on unreserved lands will be prohibited. It is, in
effect, the final passing of the great American dream of free land.
Recognizing the long term structures which would be created by the
Settlement Act, Congress provided that the Joint Federal-State Land
Use Planning Commission would function as advisory board to the State
of Alaska, the Federal Agencies and the Congress during the period of
implementation. The Commission is scheduled to self-destruct in
December of 1976 under the terms of the Act.
The new problem which Alaska and the federal government must face
is, ''What type of system can be developed which will allow for
functional management of the new joint land interests in Alaska?"
There are several aspects of land management which must cross
political boundaries if successful long term management is to be
sustained. Some of the functional aspects of land management which
must be incorporated in any regional plan to be successful are:
Watershed
management
Fish and game management
Recreational management
Natural resource management
In addition, such governmental powers as police, public health,
and transportation regulation must cross the boundaries imposed by
the Claims Settlement if rational government is to be maintained in
Alaska.
The four aspects of land management listed above were the subjects
of a three-day seminar held in Anchorage in February of this year
sponsored by the Southcentral Alaska Chapter of ASPA. These four
areas were examined because they are of the greatest import overall
in Alaska at present. While no outstanding new discoveries were made,
the interrelationship of every aspect of land management was clear to
most participants by the end of the third day. Some of the
conclusions that were reached are summarized briefly here.
Watershed managers fall into two major categories; they are those
who manage through regulation, and those who own the watersheds they
manage. Their major objectives are: to insure a supply of pure water
to input into water systems; to insure that discharges returned to
the watershed do not exceed pollution control standards; and to
control floods.
Fish and game managers are primarily concerned with maintaining
healthy populations of animals, birds and fish. To accomplish this,
they must maintain terrestrial and aquatic habitats that will support
the various species on a continuing basis. To do this, they must have
some say over uses which will have adverse effects upon habitat.
Because fish and game populations are often cyclical, the need for
habitat is a variable that requires flexibility in management.
Equally important is the provision of a suitable interface between
man and those species which he hunts, fishes, looks at, and studies.
To be successful in this area, access must be provided in some cases
and restricted in others. This restriction of access is the most
difficult part of fish and game management since wild species are
often commonwealth property, as they are in Alaska, and intrusions
against such property are difficult to regulate.
Recreation uses of land can have the highest impact of any use
except strip mining or total urbanization. Land has a carrying
capacity for various types of outdoor recreational use and zoning is
probably necessary to insure that incompatible uses are not indulging
in competition for land that can only support the one use. R1 this
competition, the machine-oriented recreationist must win and since he
requires larger amounts of land, has impact over a wider area.
Therefore, zoning normally follows the path of excluding such
recreation or limiting it.
Although it seems that natural resource development has only
recently come under intense criticism there has been throughout
history a continuing dichotomy between man's desires to develop the
land through exploitation at the expense of others and his desire to
maintain his home environment relatively unchanged from the condition
he is used to. Rock quarries and strip mines always required some
degree of economic or governmental force to win grudging acceptance
in their immediate neighborhood. The automobile and the large
earthmoving machines that gave us the power to disrupt the land
rapidly have pushed this always present tension to its present point.
Now, natural resource developers, being driven to the wall, are
rapidly becoming advocates of regional planning - on their terms.
They indulge in much discussion of alternative sources and of
rehabilitation of disturbed lands. Essentially the resource
developers still want as much freedom to explore and develop as they
can gain from other uses.
The alternatives for cooperative management in Alaska for the
future need through discussion now so that the framework for their
implementation can be incorporated in one of the three land use
planning bills presently before the Congress.
Recently, former Secretary of the Interior Hickel has again
brought forward the proposal that all federal land management
programs should be brought under one agency in order that
fractionated management in the federal sector in Alaska could be
avoided. This agency would, it is assumed, carry out the mandate of
the Congress regarding national parks, wildlife refuges, national
forests and other national priorities. Supposedly, more rational
management of these missions would be created by having one
management agency.
The result of this for the State of Alaska would be that it would
have to deal with one very powerful agency rather than several
who are just powerful. With all federal lands under one jurisdiction,
the perception of a federal state within the State of Alaska would
become even more pervasive than it is at present. While Alaska must
deal now with the Secretary of Interior ultimately on most matters of
federal lands, except for National Forests, there is a certain
advantage for the state in fact that the Secretary must take into
account the competing interests of the various land management
agencies in reaching his decisions and the state and local
governments can work through any or all of these agencies in order to
advance local positions.
If there are to be no specially designated lands and all federal
lands are to be managed as general purpose lands then this proposal
would have more validity. However, the whole concept of multiple use
and general purpose land management is in such a quandary of defining
its real aims at present that it would seem most perilous to create a
new superagency with a role to manage all federal lands on such a
basis.
Another alternative that has been discussed is to create a federal
commission to coordinate federal land management and regional
planning efforts. This would be, in effect, a resurrection of the
Federal Field Committee for Development Planning in Alaska. This
group would ideally form joint committees with state agencies in
various areas to achieve cooperative planning. This is certainly a
better alternative then the present Land-Use Planning Commission
which is forced to adopt a regional planning coordination role to
accomplish its more narrowly defined mission under the Native Claims
Settlement Act. Such a commission could act as a focus for federal
policy and would still allow the state and local governments the
option of coordination directly with agencies when necessary.
Ideally, this commission would set up joint federal state working
groups in the functional areas of land management which would result
in policy, planning and budget coordination at the five-year,
prior-year and present-year level. It would allow the present
structure to function but would put special demands upon it for
coordination. The problem that would arise would be when these
well-coordinated plans encounter the Congress and the state
legislature and become subject to the desires of those bodies. This
will be present in any system designed but a body structured like the
old Federal Field Committee is especially vulnerable since it can
only act through the budgets of its constituent members.
Another possibility is to continue the present joint Federal/State
Land Use Planning Commission with some adjustments. The commission is
presently composed of a federal co-chairman who is appointed by the
President and a state co-chairman who i5 the Governor of Alaska.
There are four federal and four state commissioners. The
commissioners serve as needed for approximately sixty days per year
while the co-chairperson positions are full time. The Governor of
Alaska has designated a person to serve in his stead.
The commission has, under the terms of the Native Claims
Settlement Act, a special relationship to the Secretary of the
Interior. The Commission is of an advisory nature only and must
implement its policies through the Secretary of the Interior if they
affect federal lands and through the Governor if state lands are at
issue. Action must be taken through the Secretary on those lands
designated for selection by Alaska's Natives.
The commission as it is presently structured serves the function
of implementing the Settlement Act. It is forced into transportation
studies and other areas because its decisions on land selections have
such long ranging effects in all parts of the Alaskan social and
economic structure. Because of its special relationship to the
Secretary and the Governor it is difficult for the commission to
coordinate functional management policies that involve other
government agencies at the federal level.
New roles and relationships must be considered for the commission
if it is to be continued past 1976. When it is no longer hampered by
the structures of its enabling legislation, the Settlement Act, it
will be possible to remove some of the present barriers to successful
coordination and policy development.
If both state and federal commissioners were appointed for terms
the commission would certainly acquire more independence in policy
development. Appointment of federal commissioners by the President
would give them more status with other departments of the federal
government. The state government could have a co-chairman appointed
in his own right serving at the pleasure of the governor and the
federal co-chairman could continue to serve at the pleasure of the
President. This would balance the independence of the commissioners
and force the commission to truly coordinate its decisions with both
the state and federal sector.
If the commission were to serve as advisor to the President rather
than the Secretary of the Interior it would then have equal status
with all federal departments and probably have an enhanced coordinate
role. The commission would continue to rely upon federal and state
agency support for most of the input to its planning system. This
would require enough core staff to coordinate and synthesize this
input for consideration by the commission .
Another proposal has been that lead agencies should be designated
in certain areas of land management. This is another variation of the
last concept examined but much weaker and more difficult to maintain
continuity through planning and budget cycles.
One final alternative to examine is for the State of Alaska to
serve as the base for cooperative management. The state government
would provide the statewide framework and the borough governments the
regional focus. This alternative would require that federal agencies
subordinate their authority in part to the state and borough planning
powers, at least to the point where these bodies would have the right
to review projected changes in federal land uses on the same basis as
any zoning change. The Alaska state legislature passed a bill in this
year's session which allows local government jurisdictions in Alaska
to zone state lands and review their uses for compatibility with
community planning goals. The same general thesis must be extended to
federal lands if this alternative for cooperative planning is to
work.
Plans are already being advanced by the state government and the
Land-Use Planning Commission to develop six planning regions within
the state based upon major hydrographic areas. Watershed management
on the statewide scale could be accomplished by utilization of these
districts. Special authorities would not be necessary if state
jurisdication in this area continued to prevail as it presently does
under Alaska law.
Fish and game management must cross political and geographic
boundaries in order to be successful. Luckily there are no major
problems with Canada at this time on species which migrate across the
boundry, and most of Alaska's problems with terrestrial species are
self-contained. Here, again, if state jurisdiction continues on its
present basis, the framework for rational management will be present.
The Alaska Department of Fish and Game is rapidly developing a
statewide system of zones for game management within which the needs
of National Parks and Wildlife Refuges can be accommodated.
Essentially the plan calls for areas designed for highest quality
hunting, areas for viewing only, areas designed to meet the
subsistence needs of all Alaskans and scientific study areas.
Recreational management under this system would involve
coordinating the needs of the National Parks Systems, the State of
Alaska Parks Systems, private investors and local communities. Some
small communities fear being deluged in a flood of tourists that
might be generated by large federal investments in the new National
Parks that will be created in Alaska in the next five years. Other
communities will welcome such investments. The residents of Alaska
fear that their own recreation needs will be derogated to meet the
demands of tourism. Alaska is familiar with what has happened in the
Caribbean and in Hawaii and does not care to repeat the experiences
of other major vacation and recreation areas if possible.
However, many of us feel that this is not a real danger since the
tourist normally follows the sun and we are not noted for that
commodity. There is no reason why, if investments in recreation are
coordinated so that one area is not overwhelmed with investments from
all sectors, federal, state and private while other areas are left
with nothing, that successful management patterns cannot be
developed. However, the future possible management pattern in this
area is not so clear as in watershed and fish and game. The National
Outdoor Recreation Plan assumes state leadership in this area but is
somewhat nebulous about how this is to be accomplished. The Alaska
Parks and Recreation Council has been created to provide a statewide
coordinating agency and this concept includes local parks and
recreation councils for local coordination. The council includes all
federal and state agencies, local governments and citizens interested
in recreation. However, it is still a nebulous concept and only two
local councils have been established.
The problems which need to be worked out on a joint basis in
achieving successful outdoor recreation patterns in Alaska are
myriad. If such problems as whether federal lands should be available
for private development the role of mechanized recreation in an area,
and the general impacts previously discussed are to be resolved, a
more positive planning mechanism must be developed for outdoor
recreation. The council system will work only if the federal and
state agencies are forced to take formal cognizance of council
actions. This is not presently the case.
It may be best that the boroughs serve as the focus for outdoor
recreation planning and that this be treated as a part of the local
planning function. If federal agencies had to secure local review and
approval of land use changes recreational uses would be included. The
economic aspects of recreational development and their impact upon
communities are not well handled at the local level at present but
receive at least as much attention as the federal and state agencies
give them. Community self-interest must be counted upon to serve as a
countervailing force one way or another in this regard.
The problems engendered by natural resource development on the
scale which will be present in Alaska in the next decade cross state
and national boundaries. The development of a United States, and,
hopefully, a continental energy policy, will govern in large part the
development of Alaska's oil, coal, and other mineral resources. The
state will need all the help it can get from land use planning
legislation at the national level to insure that good planning
standard other sectors are not sacrificed to real or apparent energy
needs. The state will also need help in maintaining the position of
its living natural resources to insure that their viability is not
sacrificed to national energy goals.
It is now becoming apparent that many Alaskans are experiencing a
surfeit of development. It may well be that national public and
private interests will demand development of Alaska at a greater pace
than its residents desire. Hopefully, the state will be able to
retain a large say in the rate of development of its minerals and
will not be forced by national policy to accept capital investments
by multinational corporations larger than can be reasonably
accommodated within the political structure of a state of 330,000
people.
The State of Alaska has been castigated by many because it has
fought against large land areas being designated for special purpose
national uses. This opposition has been brought about not so much by
the projected land uses as by a natural fear of control by the
federal agencies and the clients which control them. It is likely
that Alaska will soon be castigated by those who wish to develop
resources at a faster rate than is desired.
In any case, no matter what land use planning bills are eventually
passed by the Congress, there must be within them some role for
regional planning. In Alaska, the state framework is uniquely suited
to the regional needs and if state and borough planning resources can
be bolstered by the immediate future to a point where they can handle
the constant flood of problems in every sector, it will probably work
to the ultimate benefit of both the federal, state and private
sectors. It is not a dramatic solution involving grand new structures
but it does fit the immediate political and economic realities of
Alaska now. In a nation of 210 million, the national interest will
always be served against local interests. The need is for a structure
that will allow state and local governments to at least have the
initial determination of their destiny and to insure that their
problem will be heard by the Congress before the voices of the
multinational corporations and large interest groups drown out all
other dialogue.
Walter B. Parker
Associate in Systems Planning
Arctic Environmental Information
and Data Center
University of Alaska
Footnote
1. U. S. Federal Field Committee for Development
Planning in Alaska. Economic out look for Alaska, Anchorage, Alaska,
1971, p. 52)
|